Economic growth and balance of payments constraint in Vietnam
Alberto BAGNAI
Arsène RIEBER
Thi Anh-Dao Tran (Corresponding Author)
Abstract:
Our paper applies
a multi-country BoP constrained growth model to Vietnam for the period 1985-2010.
We find that Vietnam grew less than the rate predicted during the entire period
considered, but with different behavior for the 1998-2010 sub-period. The relative
price effect is neutral, allowing the volume effects to dominate in setting the
BoP constraint. The high income elasticities of exports enable growth in the advanced
countries to have a multiplier effect on the Vietnamese economy. However, this effect
is hindered by a high “appetite“ for imports
coming from Asia. We also assess the impact of the current crisis on Vietnam’s growth
for the period 2011-2017.
Keywords: Economic
growth, BoP-constrained growth model, Multi-country model, Asia, Vietnam.
JEL Classification:
E12, F43, O24, O53
1. INTRODUCTION
In the debate
on development, much attention has been given to the role that external trade plays
in explaining long term growth. The successful experiences of the first and second
tiers of Newly Industrializing Countries (NICs) In Asia have notably given credence
to the belief in a positive correlation between trade openness and economic performance
(World Bank, 1993). In view of this, priority has been given to market-oriented
reforms which include the reduction of trade barriers and the opening of domestic
markets to foreign competition. From the point of view of developing countries,
globalization has thus been perceived as a process whereby access to markets of
the North and inflows of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) Are considered essential
to successful integration into the world economy.
However, with
the current global crisis, a vigorous debate has risen around this development model.
Firstly, globalization of the world economy has reinforced the interdependence of
individual nations, and this may drastically change the pattern of trade inter-linkages
and price adjustment. In particular, the constraint imposed by international demand
invalidates the „small country‟ assumption, stressing the importance of demand-side factors as
determinants of countries‟ export performance (Thirlwall, 2002). The fallacy of composition
in labor-intensive manufactures aptly illustrates this argument. 1 It assumes that
if all, and in particular large developing countries, shift towards more export-oriented
strategies, there will be a risk that they encounter diminishing demand for exports
from developed countries, and that the terms of trade decline to such an extent
that the benefits of any increased volume of exports is more than offset by losses
due to lower export prices (Faini, Clavijo, & Senhadji-Semlali, 1992).
1 Cline (1982)
Pioneered the fallacy of composition argument in the context of generalized export-oriented
strategies in the Third World. See Mayer (2003) For a review of the literature.
Secondly, the
process of global economic integration followed by financial and trade liberalization
have exacerbated Balance of Payments' (BoP) Deterioration and high current account
deficits in most of the developing countries. One argument is that trade liberalization
has increased the propensity to import over time. The BoP restrictions which have
a negative impact on economic growth have been preeminent since the early 1990s.
More than ever, the developing world (including the „emerging economies‟) Has experienced BoP crises and more
than anywhere else, it is in the Low and Lower-Middle-Income (LMI) Countries that
the BoP constitutes a structural problem.
Concern in this
regard has become particularly acute in Vietnam, a development success story like
those in East Asia. The transition process to a market economy launched in 1986
with Doi Moi ( ”renovation” in
Vietnamese) Enabled Vietnam to shift from one of the poorest countries in the world
(with per capita GDP of US$98 in 1990) To a LMI country (with per capita income
of US$1,130 in 2010) In less than 20 years. Vietnam‟s economy has grown at an annual average
rate of 7.3% from 1990 through 2010, outpacing other countries in the Asian region.
The ratio of population in absolute poverty has fallen from 58% in 1993 to 14.5%
in 2008, while most indicators of welfare have improved (World Bank, 2011). Structural
change has involved the shift of workers from low productivity agriculture to labor
intensive manufacturing.
Behind the story,
integration in the world economy has been the key driver of Vietnam‟s economic and social development. The
country has gone through a far-reaching transformation from an inward-looking planned
economy to one that is globalized and market-based. In the mid-1990s, Vietnam strengthened
its international integration by entering discussions about bilateral, regional
and multilateral agreements in trade and investment. The country formally completed
World Trade Organization (WTO) Accession in late 2006, culminating a long process
of efforts to integrate the national economy into global markets (Abbott, Bentzen,
& Tarp, 2009). These changes have had dramatic implications for trade and investment
flows: Exports and imports as a share of GDP increased tenfold from 1988 to 2008,
representing respectively 77.5% and 87.8% in 2010. Over the last two decades, average
growth rates of exports and imports were 16.4% and 18% respectively, compared with
7.3% for GDP.
Although the
currency and financial crises that hit East Asia in 1997-98 had less effect on the
Vietnamese economy than what had been feared, further integration into the world
and regional economies was thought to make a substantial contribution to economic
growth in the decade ahead. This process then enhanced Vietnam‟s attractiveness for foreign direct and
portfolio investments. While earlier capital flows following the end of Soviet aid
were allowed by the lift of US embargo in 1994, a sudden surge in FDI inflows occurred
with the country‟s accession to the WTO, encouraging further short term inflows
of capital. With the equivalent of 33.7% of GDP, capital inflows in 2007 were four
times higher relative to GDP than anything China had experienced since the beginning
of its own reform process (World Bank, 2008).
(Insert Figure
1 here)
However, with
rapid growth and massive capital inflows, the country has experienced growing macroeconomic
turbulence in recent years. Between 2005 and 2007, the current account deficit increased
from 0.9% to 9.8% of GDP (Figure 1) While the capital account surplus increased
even faster, from 4.8% to 24.6% of GDP (World Bank, 2008). Net positive capital
inflows have led to demand pressures and subsequent changes in relative prices.
Inflation rates averaged 16% a year between 2008 and 2011, asset price bubbles emerged
while the country was coping with persistent pressures on its currency, loss of
international reserves and capital flight.
According to
the World Bank (2011), the government addressed these macroeconomic imbalances by
relying almost exclusively on tight monetary policy, but it has yet to tackle their
root causes. From our point of view, the analysis of macroeconomic instability in
Vietnam cannot be dissociated from the country‟s BoP position. Substantial current account
deficits and the rising capital inflows to finance them played a significant part
in disturbing macroeconomic stability. Based on these stylized facts, the question
that naturally arises here is whether the country is growing faster than the rate
allowed by its BoP equilibrium.
To this purpose,
our paper examines the long-run relationship between economic growth and the current
account balance equilibrium by relying on the BoP constrained growth model, originally
developed by Thirlwall (1979). While the conventional theories of growth rely on
neoclassical models to explain supply-side issues originating from factor accumulation,
technological progress or the contribution of productivity growth, this alternative
approach emphasizes demand-driven mechanisms which limit growth. It postulates that
the BoP equilibrium of a country is the primary constraint on its economic growth
in the long-run.
However, our
study fills a number of gaps in the literature. From a theoretical point of view,
the analytical framework proposed here improves over previous attempts to extend
Thirlwall‟s
law to a multi-country setting, by allowing for a more rigorous disaggregation of
the BoP constraint among different partner areas (Bagnai, Rieber, & Tran, 2012).
More precisely, we verify the importance of the different channels of transmission
involved (real growth, changes in relative prices and import/export market shares).
From an empirical point of view, the paper provides fresh evidence on growth performance
in Vietnam using annual data from 1985 to 2010. There have been a lot of studies
applying the BoP constrained growth model to individual countries and groups of
countries (Thirlwall, 2012). But to our knowledge, no empirical study has yet tested
the model for Vietnam; Neither has there been an analysis of long run growth since
the country‟s
accession to the WTO.
The paper is
structured as follows. Section 2 presents the theoretical background. Section 3
describes the methodological aspects of the estimation process. Section 4 presents
and interprets the empirical results. Considering the recent global slowdown, Section
5 attempts some simulation exercises to forecast the impact of external shocks on
Vietnam‟s future growth. Section 6 summarizes
our main results and concludes.
THE THEORETICAL BACKGROUND
(a) Thirlwall’s Law and the developing countries
The relationship
between exports and economic growth is among the richest debates present in development
macroeconomics. While it has been widely explored in the economic literature (both
in the light of international trade theory and growth theory), the relationship
between exports and economic growth is focused here from the point of view of the
BoP-related factors. For most developing countries, foreign exchange is a scarce
resource whose shortage, determined by persistent BoP deficits, may impair growth.
The BoP constrained growth model postulates that overall growth of an open economy
is primarily constrained by the need to generate foreign exchange, and emphasizes
the role of demand as the driving force for domestic growth. According to Thirlwall
(1979), the relationship between the growth rate of a country and its BoP is the
fundamental law for growth because the BoP sets an upper limit to growth compatible with trade balance
equilibrium. In contrast to the other components of aggregate demand, export is
the only one whose expansion stimulates economic growth without leading into a deterioration
of the BoP. The role of export performance is then emphasized because no other component
of aggregate demand provides the foreign exchange to pay for import requirements
associated with the expansion of output (Hussain, 1999).
Thirlwall's Law is expressed in these terms: “In the long-term,
no country can grow faster than the rate consistent with the balance of payments
equilibrium on the current account unless it can finance ever-growing deficit which,
in general, it cannot“. Consequently, there is a growth rate that a country
cannot exceed for prolonged periods, because if it does, it will quickly run into
BoP difficulties. This is the ”BoP
equilibrium growth rate”.
In its basic
form, the BoP-constrained growth model is a simple model which derives from the
demand functions for imports and exports:
(1) YEPPMf
(2) ZPEPXf
(3) MEP = PXf
Where M and
X are imports and exports in real terms, P are domestic prices, E
is the nominal exchange rate (the price in domestic currency of one unit of foreign
currency), Pf are foreign prices in foreign currency, Y is real domestic
GDP, and Z is world real GDP. The positive parameters , ,
denote respectively the price and income elasticities of imports and exports.
Eq. (3) States that in the long run, the current account of the BoP must be balanced.
2
2 To keep things
simple, we ignore net incomes from abroad in the theoretical discussion.
By taking growth
rates, substituting (1) And (2) Into equation (3), and by assuming constant relative
prices, we solve for the domestic income growth rate which is compatible with the
BoP equilibrium:
(4) XZYBP
Where a dot over
the variables indicates growth rates.
Thirlwall‟s Law postulates that the rate of growth
of an open economy which is consistent with BoP equilibrium (denoted here) Is determined
by the growth rate of its volume of exports divided by the income elasticity of
imports. Put differently, the BoP equilibrium growth rate depends on the growth
of world income and on the relative size of the income elasticities of demand for
exports and imports. If a country‟s growth rate is lower than, the country
will accumulate trade surpluses and will be a net capital exporter. Conversely,
if its actual growth exceeds, the current account will worsen and the country will
become a net capital importer, implying growth of BPYBPYBPY capital inflows:
But this cannot continue indefinitely. 3 An economy is “BoP-constrained” whenever its growth rate must adjust downwards to
maintain the BoP equilibrium.
3 However, there
is an asymmetry in the adjustment process resulting from the BoP position. In contrast
to a BoP deficit, a country with a BoP surplus can accumulate foreign exchange reserves
almost indefinitely whenever it grows lower than the BoP equilibrium growth rate,
so that there is no pressure on the country to raise its growth rate until it reaches
its upper limit.
Two remarks are
worth emphasizing at this stage. Firstly, the model assumes that developing countries
operate at less than full capacity, as a result of the lack of foreign exchange
and other structural bottlenecks. However, although it places emphasis on growth
in demand to raise capacity utilization, it does not mean that supply factors are
unimportant. Rather, any production bottleneck that restricts export growth will
be damaging for growth (Felipe, McCombie, & Naqvi, 2009). But the dominant constraint
is the external constraint.
Secondly, this
approach provides a rationale for an export-led growth model because exports are
the only one component of demand whose growth simultaneously relaxes the BoP constraint.
Therefore, policies designed to increase the income elasticity of export (concern
the changing composition of exports and the measures to improve the performance
of exports. But these efforts could be hindered by the country‟s “appetite
for imports” (), i. E. The degree of dependence on imports. This implies
that the same rates of export growth in different countries do not produce the same
rates of economic growth, because of the existence of different income elasticities
of imports.
The theoretical
background proposed in our study will extend the original BoP-constrained growth
model in two ways. Firstly, the hypothesis of relative price constancy in Eq. (4)
Is contradicted by the evidence that developing countries‟ terms of trade are trending in the long
run, in support of the Prebisch-Singer hypothesis (Faini et al., 1992; Sapsford
& Chen, 1998). Such price changes appear to be relevant in Vietnam, where the
abolition of price and exchange rate controls in 1987, followed by international
integration, marked substantial adjustment in relative prices (Figure 2). Therefore,
we decided to include the role of relative price changes in the analytical framework.
(Insert Figure
2 here)
Our second extension
deals with the income elasticities of exports and imports: With a rise in for
instance, will decrease and tighten the BoP constraint. However, does the original
Thirlwall's Law provide a unified framework for explaining any change in this behavioral
parameter?
In the original
model, the long-term economic growth of an open economy is determined by the rate
of growth of aggregate exports, which is, in turn, determined exogenously by the
given growth of “world income“. In practice
however, an individual country trades goods and services with a number of partner
countries, and each bilateral trade relations may have different outcomes. Since
the economic growth of a country depends on the growth rate of other countries through
the BoP constraint, this mutual interdependence should be captured in a model with
multilateral trade relations between the individual country and blocks of countries.
By the same token, the import behavior should be differentiated among the selling
countries to assess how geography can be a determinant of trade relations. In view
of this, our theoretical background extends the original Thirlwall‟s Law by developing a multi-country setting
both at the export and the import sides. By doing so, we will be able to identify
the structural parameters and what they say about the BoP constrained growth rate.
(b) A multi-country version of Thirlwall’s Law
The analytical
extension is made by assuming that a given country i has n trading
partners, which requires disaggregation of the model to allow for several countries.
The bilateral trade flows of country i was disaggregated into 5 main partner
areas: J = A, B, C, D, E (see Appendix A for country grouping). Eq.
(3) Which states the current account equilibrium becomes:
EDCBAjijjijEDCBAjijiMPEXP,,,,,,,,
Where Pi
are country i export prices, Xij is the real demand of partner j
for country i exports, Eij is the bilateral nominal exchange rate,
Pj are export prices in j, and Mij are country i imports
from partner j. Assuming away accounting problems, we consider that Xij
= Mji, i. E. The exports from country i to partner j
must equal the imports of the latter from the former. This ”mirror flows“ identity, which is routinely exploited as a convenient
simplification in a number of multi-country models, offers some practical advantages
in terms of data collection and of the specification of the demand functions. Notably,
it enables us to work only with import functions.
By exploiting
this symmetry, we reformulate the model as follows:
(5) IjijijijiijYPEPM
(6) JijijijijjiYPPEM
(7) jijjijjjiiMPEMP
Where, in addition
to the previous variables, ij and ij are respectively the price
and income elasticities of country i imports from partner j, Mji
is the real demand of partner j for imports from country i (i. E.
Exports from country i to partner j), ji and ji are
the corresponding price and income elasticities, and Yj is partner j
real GDP.
Taking the growth
rates in (7) We obtain:
(8) jijjijijjjijiiMPEMP
Where: (j
= A, B, C, D, E) IijjjijijiXXMMvjijjijijjijijMPEMPE
ji and
ij are respectively the market shares of partner j in country i
total exports (in volume) And in country i total imports (in value).
Solving for the
growth rate of country i as before, and denoting Rij = Pi/
(EijPj) The bilateral relative prices (i. E. The ratio of domestic
to foreign prices expressed in domestic currency), we obtain a multi-country version
of Thirlwall‟s
Law:
(9) EDCBAjijijEDCBAjjjijiEDCBAjjijiijijijBPiYRY,,,,,,,,,,,,,1
The multi-country
specification allows us to separately assess the contribution of each group of countries
to country i growth rate predicted by the model. We can observe that the
numerator of the multi-country law features both a relative price effect (whose
sign depends on the market-shares-weighted bilateral price elasticities), and a
volume effect (a weighted sum of real export growth). The denominator instead features
a weighted sum of bilateral income elasticities of imports that corresponds to country
i aggregate “appetite for imports”,.
In other words, the aggregate income elasticity, that plays a crucial role in the
single country version of Thirlwall‟s law, is nothing but a “black
box” summarizing behavioral parameters
that are likely be subject to changes. jijij
Another important
feature of the multi-country law is that it cannot be decomposed in bilateral terms.
In fact, bilateral deficits are not constrained per se: As a consequence,
the aggregate BoP constraint cannot be expressed as an additive function of
bilateral balances. Having said this, one can measure however the contribution of
partner‟s j variables (either in country
i export market or import demand) To changes in the aggregate BoP
constraint of country i (see Bagnai et al., 2012).
DATA AND ESTIMATION ISSUES
In a first step,
the long-run elasticities featuring the BoP constraint are estimated through the
following ten log-linear bilateral trade equations:
mj, t = j + i, j rj, t + i,
j yi, t + Uj, t (j = A, B, C, D, E)
xj, t = j j, i
rj, t + j, i yj, t + Ej, t (j = A,
B, C, D, E)
Where lower case
letters indicate natural logs of the corresponding variables (therefore, rj,
t = pi, t – ei, j, t – pj, t), and uj, t and ej,
t are error terms.
Appendix B provides the data sources and definitions
that are used for estimation. In order to estimate the long-run elasticities by
cointegration, we first need to ascertain whether the Data Generating Process (DGP)
Of each series features a stochastic trend. The test was performed following the
procedure suggested by Elder and Kennedy (2001). The rationale of this procedure,
as well as the results, are reported in Appendix C. Summing up, all the time
series involved in the estimation of the trade equations for Vietnam turn out to
possess a unit root.
Having established
the presence of stochastic trends in the DGP of our time series, we tested for the
existence of a long-run relation between the relevant variables by the usual Engle
and Granger (1987) Cointegrating residual ADF (CRADF) Test. If this
test rejected the null of non-cointegration, we took the estimated elasticities
as the relevant long-run parameters. If instead the ordinary cointegration test
failed to reject the null of non-cointegration, we hypothesized that the non-rejection
could depend on the presence of a structural break in the long-run parameters. In
order to cope with this, we applied the cointegration estimator proposed by Gregory
and Hansen (1996), which tests the null of non-cointegration against the alternative
of cointegration in the presence of a structural break of unknown date. The breaks
are modeled using the dummy variable t = I (t> [T]),
where I is the indicator function, T is the sample size (T=24,
except for the exports to the US) 4, the relative timing of the change point,
and [. ] the integer part function. The Gregory and Hansen procedure takes into
account several possible alternative models, featuring a break in the intercept
only (the “level“ shift), or in the intercept
and in the slopes (the ”regime“ shift).
Moreover, some alternative modes include a time trend, which in turn can be modeled
with or without a break.
4 Since bilateral
trade data with the US were subject to embargo until 1994 and only started thereafter,
we were not able to apply the Gregory and Hansen procedure to these equations.
Owing to the
relatively limited dimension of our sample, we decided to test the null of non-cointegration
against the simplest alternative, that of “level”
shift, where only the intercept is affected by the structural break. 5
5 Testing the
null of non-cointegration against other alternatives led to non-rejection, or rejection
with larger p-values, or models with imprecisely estimated elasticities. It is worth
noting that in our case, the so-called “regime”
shift alternative entails the loss of three (instead of one) Degrees of freedom
(corresponding to the three shift parameters).
Taking the import
equation as an example, the “level“ shift
is modeled as follows:
Mj, t = j0 + j0t +
i, j rj, t + i, j yi, t + Uj, t (j = A,
B, C, D, E)
Where j0
is the intercept in the first regime, t is the shift dummy variable defined
before, j0 is the intercept shift, so that the value taken by the intercept
in the second subsample is j1 = j0 + j0. It is worth noting
that in the ”level“ shift case the income
and price elasticities are unaffected, which implies that a structural break of
this kind has no impact on the BoP constraint (as the relevant elasticities remain
constant throughout the sample).
The test statistic
is evaluated as ADF* =, where ADF () Is the cointegrating ADF
statistic corresponding to the shift occurring in [T]. In other words, ADF*
Is the smallest among all the ADF statistics that can be evaluated across
all possible dates of structural breaks. The reported break date T1 = [T]
refers to the last year of the first regime (i. E., the change in the parameter
occurs between T1 and T1+ 1). rADFinf
RESULTS
(a) The estimates of the long-run elasticities
Tables 1 to 4
report the estimation results, starting from the import equations. The Engle-Granger
CRADF (reported in Table 1), was unable to reject the null of non-cointegration,
with the limited exception of the imports from the US, where the null is rejected
at the 10% significance level. In most cases, the relative price term is small and
statistically insignificant. The Gregory-Hansen procedure confirms that bilateral
import flows are rather inelastic to changes in relative prices (Table 2). The structural
breaks in the bilateral import equations are all upward level shifts, with the only
exception of the “Rest of the World” (ROW)
Case, that features a downward level shift after 1990. This structural break with
level shifts makes sense from an economic point of view. The year 1991 corresponds
to the collapse of the Soviet bloc countries, forcing Vietnam to reform its trade
relations. The country adjusted by shifting its bilateral trade flows from former
socialist countries towards Western countries and the Asian neighbors.
(Insert Tables
1 to 4 here)
As far as the
bilateral export equations are concerned, the results are similar, with two differences:
The equations appear to be more stable (non-cointegration is strongly rejected against
a stable alternative in two cases, the Rest of Asia and the US), and the relative
price elasticity is statistically significant in a number of cases (while it was
never found to be significant in the bilateral import equations). As shown in Table
3, the Engle-Granger procedure rejects the null of non-cointegration in the cases
of the Rest of Asia, USA, and ROW (in the last case only at the 10% level). In the
latter two cases the price elasticity, although correctly signed, is found to be
statistically insignificant (although marginally in the ROW case). In the remaining
cases, the Gregory-Hansen procedure rejects the null of non-cointegration against
the alternative of cointegration with an upward level shift (Table 4).
Despite using
a relatively short sample (in terms of number of observations), all the relevant
elasticities are estimated very precisely, with Student‟s t typically ranging from about
5 to about 20. This result is consistent with the fact that as far as cointegration
estimates are concerned, the sample length (in calendar terms) Is more important
than the number of observations (Otero & Smith, 2000). (Insert Table 5 here)
Table 5 summarizes
the long-run elasticities that will be used to calculate the predicted growth rate
for Vietnam. In brief, all the income elasticities are statistically significant
and correctly signed, but their effects differ depending upon the partners and the
trade considered. The highest values come from the income elasticities of the developed
partners‟ demand for Vietnam‟s exports (the US, the Rest of Asia and
the EU) And, additionally, there is evidence for higher income elasticities of exports
than imports (with the notable exception of the Developing Asia, as will be discussed
later). This implies that any favorable change in the Northern partners‟ income (especially in the US with an
export elasticity of 11.7) Will have a great role in relaxing Vietnam‟s BoP constraint through the export demand.
The higher value of income elasticities of exports than imports means that with
unchanged relative prices and market shares, if Vietnam grows at the same rate as
its trading partners, the corresponding trade balance will improve.
Another picture
that emerges is one where variations in the relative prices do not matter in Vietnam‟s imports, neither in the country‟s exports to the US and the ROW. This
means that in the long-run, a large part of foreign goods and services are imported
regardless of changes in their prices. This is explained by the structure of Vietnam‟s imports, where a large part is dominated
by production goods (semi-final products, intermediate and capital goods) That are
not produced domestically. On the other hand, any competitive devaluation that decreases
domestic prices relative to foreign ones will only boost exports to the Developing
Asia, and slightly to the Rest of Asia and the EU.
(b) The BoP equilibrium growth rate
A second step
consists in comparing the average growth rates predicted by the BoP-constrained
growth model () With the actual rates (): The purpose is to test whether or not
the country‟s
growth was constrained by the BoP-related factors over the period 1985-2010. However,
since most of the Asian countries were affected by the economic recession that hit
the region after 1997, we BPYY split our time series into two sub-periods: Before
(1985-1997) And after (1998-2010) The East Asian crisis.
(Insert Table
6 here)
Table 6 reports
the elements needed for the evaluation of the BoP equilibrium growth rate following
Eq. (9). Broadly speaking, Vietnam‟s actual growth rate was below the constrained
one during the entire period considered: 6.9% compared to 8.6% on average. This
indicates that Vietnam was respecting its BoP constraint. This result can be explained
looking at Eq. (9). The estimation results showed that the coefficients of the relative
price term are statistically insignificant in all import equations and in exports
to the USA and the ROW, allowing us to remove them from the estimated equations
(ij = Di = Ei = 0). Hence, the relative price effect in the numerator of Eq.
(9) Is very small, involving income changes to dominate in defining the BoP constraint.
The export volume effect (i. E., the second term in the numerator) Contributes
to an increase in the annual growth rate by 1.53 percentage point in aggregate,
counter-balancing the adverse but minor relative price effect (-0.001 in aggregate).
A closer look at Eq. (9) Shows that the volume effect depends on bilateral income
elasticities and market shares of exports. The high income elasticities of exports
create a favorable environment, allowing for instance growth of income in the Rest
of Asia (which is the largest export market over the full sample, with a share of
33.2%) To have a multiplier effect on Vietnam‟s economic growth through the term νBiπBi.
However, the denominator reached 1.78 for the whole period under consideration.
So, in view of a small effect of relative prices, the divergence between Vietnam‟s actual growth rate and the growth of
real exports is explained by the high “appetite”
of domestic demand for imports, mainly coming from the Asian area (high income elasticity
of import from the Developing Asia, and the heaviest import market share from the
Rest of Asia).
Substantial differences
emerge however, when we look at averages for the two sub-periods. While the actual
growth rate displays a surprising stability (in view of the fact that the sample
includes the East Asian crisis), the constraint shifts between the first and the
second subsample. Prior to the East Asian crisis, Vietnam grew at a rate below
the constrained rate, with a spread of 4.1 percentage points. The large part of
trade that occurred with the former Soviet bloc countries may partially explain
the much higher growth rate predicted by the model for this sub-period. Still, the
sustained rapid growth achieved by the country after Doi Moi illustrates
a situation where productive capacity was under-utilized within the planned economy
and then, the transition reforms brought resources into production. Thus, Vietnam
between 1985 and 1997 may be described as capacity constrained, where the country
was growing at its capacity growth rate without encountering BoP difficulties.
The reverse occurs
in the recent sub-period, where Vietnam‟s actual growth rate marginally exceeded the constrained rate (6.9% compared to
6.7%), resulting in capital inflows to bridge the financing gap. The spread between
the BoP equilibrium and the actual averages, which decreased from 4.1 to about -0.2
percentage point, can be taken as evidence of increased demand constraint on Vietnam‟s growth. As a matter of fact, the constrained
growth rate fell from 11% to 6.7% after the Asian crisis, while the country actually
kept growing at 6.9%. So, a question arises here: Why was Vietnam‟s equilibrium growth rate falling? Which
partners were responsible for this and through which channel of transmission?
The previous
table also reports the contribution of the various components of the BoP equilibrium
growth rate; We can then analyze their changes between the two sub-periods. Firstly,
the strongest effect which contributed to tightening Vietnam‟s BoP came from the volume of exports
destined to the Rest of Asia (partner B). With the heaviest weight in the bilateral
income elasticity of exports, the Rest of Asia (namely, the developed Asia) Sustained
Vietnam‟s export growth over the whole period
considered. However, its GDP growth rate declined by 2 percentage points in the
second sub-period, eroding Vietnam‟s export performance. A bilateral trade
agreement signed in 2000 between Vietnam and the US evidently boosted Vietnamese
exports. But this only partially compensated the former negative effect: While the
US contribution increased tenfold (from 0.3 percentage point to 3.8), the export
volume effect for the Rest of Asia fell to one third (from 9.6 to 3.2).
The second reason,
which explains Vietnam‟s tighter BoP constraint since the Asian crisis, is related to
the structural parameters involved in the country‟s appetite for imports. The denominator
of Eq. (9) Rose from 1.54 to 2.04 between the two sub-periods. While Vietnam was
mainly dependent on imports from the Rest of Asia over the whole period considered,
the most relevant change came from the share of the Developing Asia in Vietnam‟s total imports. As it climbed from 10.1%
before the Asian crisis to 29.6% in the last sub-period, the corresponding weighted
bilateral elasticity rose sharply from 0.31 to 0.9. This indicates a strong asymmetry
in bilateral trade relations between Vietnam and its developing neighbors: The country
exports mainly to the advanced countries (with the highest export sensitivity to
income changes for the US), but any rise in domestic activity will imply a sustained
growth of imports from the developing Asia. Figure 3 depicts the evolution of Vietnam‟s trade market shares over the period
considered: As bilateral flows grew at different rates, the market shares evolved
accordingly. Even if the bilateral income elasticities remained constant, the denominator
changed over time and impacted negatively on the country‟s BoP position.
(Insert Figure
3 here)
These evolutions
are consistent with the pattern of economic integration in East Asia, where latecomer
countries like Vietnam joined the international production networks organized by
multinational firms. The ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA) Joined by Vietnam in 2001
removed trade barriers throughout the region and a further step has been taken forward
to transform the free trade area into a single market with the establishment of
an ASEAN Economic Community by 2015 (Fujita, Kuroiwa, & Kumagai, 2011). Meanwhile,
subsequent bilateral FTA with China, South Korea and Japan (that is, ASEAN+ 3) Was
launched in 2005,2007 and 2008 respectively, followed by India, Australia and New
Zealand (the ASEAN+ 6 grouping). All these countries are taken into account in our
country grouping and show the empirical relevance of our study.
In line with
a fragmentation process which has proliferated in the region, the UNCTAD (2008)
Showed that the largest wave of production-sharing schemes has been found in East
and South-East Asia, often as a part of triangular (South–South–North) Trading network.
The region is now functioning as a world factory, trading production goods (especially
parts and components used for export-oriented industries) Within the region, and
then exporting final products to overseas destinations. 6 Vietnam, as a newcomer
in the production network, has experienced dramatic changes according to the region‟s production-oriented trade structure.
After the regional crisis in 1997, its appetite for imports coming from Asia reached
1.66 out of 2.04 in the denominator. Our study finds evidence in support of Sepheri
and Akram-Lodhi (2005), whose estimates for import behavior demonstrated that Vietnam‟s growth is highly dependent on imported
capital and intermediate goods. Thus, the greater the rate of capacity utilization
through exports, the greater the extent of necessary imports to keep production
moving.
6 According to
Fujita et al. (2011), East Asia absorbs only a quarter of the consumption
goods exported from Asian countries.
IMPACT OF THE CURRENT GLOBAL CRISIS
(a) Filtering
A last step of
our study assesses the impact of the current global crisis on Vietnam‟s economic growth. More precisely, the
over-reliance on the “Northern“ partners‟ GDP for exports has been questioned since
2008. In order to address this issue, we look at the evolution over time of the
BoP-constrained rate. Since the BoP constraint is in its nature a long-run constraint,
we take into account the long-run component of the relevant variables, and compare
it with an estimate of the long-run growth rate.
The long-run
component of each series was extracted using the Hodrick and Prescott (1997) Filter.
The filter computes the smoothed (long-run) Component st of a series yt
by minimizing the variance of the deviation of yt from st, subject
to a penalty that constrains the second differences of the smoothed series. The
long-run component st thus minimizes the following expression:
1221112TtttttTtttsssssy
The parameter
equals 100, i. E. The value suggested by Hodrick and Prescott (1997) When
dealing with annual data.
(Insert Figure
4 here)
The filtered
series were then inputted in Eq. (9), providing us with a time-varying estimate
of the BoP constraint. The estimate allows us to confirm the previous results (Figure
4). After successful transition reforms through Doi Moi, Vietnam grew at
an impressive rate. From a capacity constrained growth before 1993, the country
grew almost at the same rate as the one predicted by the model until 2005 and then
switched to a position where it is BoP constrained in its growth. This is not because
it grew too fast as the historical rates remained almost stable, but because growth
in the different components of demand has contributed to tightening the BoP constraint
since 2005. The BoP-constrained growth rate model can explain this relevant change.
Export growth made a significant contribution to GDP growth, but given the import-intensive
pattern of growth, the greater the rate of export growth, the greater the extent
of imports, and this contributed to deteriorating the BoP position. This is especially
relevant in Vietnam, whose export growth was affected by economic slowdown in the
Rest of Asia; Whereas the import growth was simultaneously accelerated by the process
of regional integration (notably towards Developing Asia). Our previous decomposition
allowed us to identify the international mechanisms through which Vietnam‟s BoP position worsened, related to the
nature of the country‟s trade partnership.
(b) Growth targets and the global economic turmoil
Vietnam‟s Socio-Economic Development Strategy
(SEDS) For 2011-2020 identifies the country‟s key priorities over the current decade.
The overall goal is for Vietnam to lay the foundations for a modern, industrialized
society by 2020. Accordingly, the government aspires to achieve a per capita income
level of 3,000 current US dollars by that year. This translates into a nearly 10%
annual growth in per capita nominal GDP over the decade (World Bank, 2011). Under
the five-year Socio-Economic Development Plan 2011-2015 (SEDP), the Vietnamese National
Assembly set a target for real GDP growth of around 6.5-7% annually to meet this
ambitious target. The total export receipts are expected to increase by 13%. Gross
capital accumulation would occupy 33.5–35% of GDP in this period, while the trade
deficit rate would be gradually reduced from 2012 onwards and is expected to be
10% of total export turnover by 2015.
The question
addressed here is whether the government‟s medium-run growth target is achievable
in the context of a weaker global economic environment, and how the foreign exchange
requirements will be filled to meet this target. To this purpose, we depart from
the last assessment of GDP growth edited by the International Monetary Fund (IMF,
2012). We constructed our baseline scenario by compiling the IMF‟s medium-term projections for the period
2011-2017 with the filtered series for import and export market shares. 7 The corresponding
BoP equilibrium growth rate is calculated by substituting our estimates of the long-run
income and price elasticities.
7 Due to the
low relative price effect, we neglect it in our simulations.
(Insert Table
7 here)
According to
IMF projections, growth prospects differ across the partner areas: While the Developing
Asia is expected to maintain a high rate (7.8% per year on average), activity in
the Northern partners (the Rest of Asia, the EU and the USA) Will remain rather
low. The relatively high growth rate in the ROW is attributable to the recent dynamic
expansion of South–South trade, providing developing countries with a favorable
external economic climate for export expansion (Bagnai et al., 2012). Vietnam
is expected to continue growing at a rate of 6.7% per year, which is consistent
with the government‟s target (Table 7).
Compared with
the 1998-2010 sub-period, we can see in our baseline scenario that, provided that
all the partner areas confirm the growth rates projected by the IMF for the period
2011-2017, Vietnam‟s BoP constraint would be relaxed by high demand growth in the
Rest of Asia, the US and the ROW. The resulting growth rate predicted by the model
lifts up (8.2%), enabling the country to achieve the growth target. In other words,
the trade partnership through which Vietnam has integrated the global and regional
economies, allows the government to achieve the medium growth target without encountering
BoP problems.
However, in case
the current crisis in the euro area does not lead to visible improvement in the
external environment, this relevant change could be reversed. In this perspective,
three scenarios are compared here. Scenario 1 assumes a sharp recession in
the world economy, with a decrease in all partners‟ GDP growth by 1 percentage point. Under
scenario 2, the same slowdown in GDP growth specifically affects the Northern
partners (the Rest of Asia, the US and the EU). Finally, scenario 3 assesses
the geographical aspect of Vietnam‟s trade integration and supposes that
the Asian area is able to avoid the economic turmoil.
Under scenario
1, recession in all partner areas and the resulting slower demand for Vietnam‟s exports will tighten the BoP constraint.
As a result, the projected foreign exchange requirements to meet the growth target
will imply heavier reliance on capital inflows. Under scenario 2, when only
the Northern partners are affected by the economic turmoil, Vietnam‟s BoP constraint is less binding; But
the corresponding growth rate (5.5%) Remains lower than the government‟s target and far lower than the growth
rate estimated in the baseline. In other words, a demand-led expansion in South–South
trade may be a weak alternative locomotive of export expansion. Whatever the scenario
undertaken, the ongoing recession reveals the vulnerability of Vietnam‟s growth to the external economic climate,
as the production networks built in the Asian area work to its disadvantage. To
illustrate this argument, scenario 3 results in more optimistic projections
when assuming that the Asian area is prevented from the global crisis. Vietnam‟s BoP equilibrium growth rate is close
to the target (6.2% against 6.5%), allowing the government to achieve the medium
growth rate with few capital inflows to bridge the financing gap. In other words,
continued robust economic expansion in the Asian region would attenuate the negative
impact on Vietnam of what would otherwise be a global economic downturn.
CONCLUSION
Vietnam has made
important progress in achieving economic and social development over the past two
decades. The country‟s accession to the WTO paved the way to greater market liberalization
and foreign investment inflows. However, recent developments in Vietnam‟s economic conditions suggest that the
country‟s BoP problems come from its integration
into global and regional economies. In the face of rapid growth with massive capital
accumulation like in Vietnam, the connection between growth and BoP cannot be ignored.
In view of this,
our paper examines the long-run relationship between economic growth and the current
account balance equilibrium by relying on a multi-country BoP constrained growth
model. The question that is addressed here is whether the country grows faster than
the rate allowed by its BoP equilibrium, and what are the international factors
that could prevent any attempt to achieve a sustained growth of rate. The theoretical
background proposed in the paper provides a convenient analytical framework to explore
BoP-related limits to Vietnam‟s growth. It then contributes to the ongoing discussion on some
of the most pressing issues about the growth process of developing countries: Does
participation in the globalized economy through export-led growth contribute to
relaxing the BoP constraint?
The model specified
was estimated using annual data for the period between 1985 and 2010. Our results
show that Vietnam grew less than the rate predicted during the entire period considered.
However, the model yielded different behavior for the 1998-2010 sub-period, where
the country appeared to be BoP constrained in its growth. In addition, a general
picture that emerges is one where the relative price effect is neutral, allowing
the volume effects to dominate in setting the BoP constraint: I. E. It is
income that adjusted in order to maintain the BoP equilibrium. The high income elasticities
of exports enable growth in the advanced countries to have a multiplier effect on
the Vietnamese economy. This suggests that Vietnam has partially benefited from
a change in bilateral or multilateral trade policies with those partners. However,
growth is hindered by the high ”appetite“
of the Vietnamese economy for imports, mainly coming from the whole of Asia. The
latter features a production-oriented trade structure which has proliferated in
the region, often as a part of triangular (South–South–North) Trading network. In
light of the diagnostics, a last step addressed the impact of global recession on
Vietnam‟s growth for the period 2011-2017. With
slower demand for exports, the BoP constraint becomes more binding whatever growth
projections in the partner areas. However, the capital inflows needed to fill the
foreign exchange gap are more limited when the Asian partners keep growing and remain
unaffected by the global economic turmoil.
A country‟s trade integration offers both the prospect
of faster growth and the risk of greater turbulence. For most of the developing
countries, exports have become the main driver of economic growth: Since exports
represent a source of foreign exchange, the analysis developed here provides a rationale
for an export-led growth strategy. However, our results suggest that this strategy
is highly vulnerable to the external economic environment. Vietnam‟s growing “appetite for imports” is also a worrying concern: To keep pace with
the globalizing economy, the country will need to reconcile its financing needs
with a prudent reliance on foreign saving. To the extent that the outward orientation
of the country does not determine a faster increase in imports, one source of growth
finance is export revenue, because it is the only one component of demand that can
pay for the import content of all the components.
Finally, there is a need for stronger export diversification to ensure stable revenue
for imported inputs requirements. The ability to develop exports holds the key to
reconciling financing needs with macroeconomic stability in an open developing economy.
REFERENCES
Abbott, P., Bentzen,
J., & Tarp, F. (2009). Trade and development: Lessons from Vietnam‟s past trade agreements. World Development,
37 (2), 341-353.
Bagnai, A., Rieber,
A., & Tran, T. A. D. (2012). Generalized BoP constrained growth and South-South
trade in Sub-Saharan Africa. In E. Soukiazis, & P. A. Cerqueira (Eds.), Models
of Balance of Payments Constrained Growth: History, Theory and Empirical Evidence
(pp. 113-143). Basingstoke: Palgrave MacMillan, forthcoming.
Campbell, J.
Y, & Perron, P. (1991). Pitfalls and opportunities: What macroeconomists should
know about unit roots. NBER Macroeconomics Annuals 1991 (vol. 6, pp. 141-201). MIT
Press.
Cline, W. R.
(1982). Can the East Asian Model of Development be generalized? World Development,
10 (2), 81–90.
Dickey, D., &
Fuller, W. (1979). Distribution of the estimators for autoregressive time-series
with a unit root. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 74,427-431.
Dolado, J., Jenkinson,
T., & Sosvilla-Rivero, S. (1990). Cointegration and unit roots. Journal of
Economic Surveys, 4,249–73.
Elder, J., &
Kennedy, P. E. (2001). Testing for unit roots: What should students be taught? Journal
of Economic Education, 32,137-46.
Engle, R. F.,
& Granger, C. W. J. (1987). Cointegration and error correction: Representation,
estimation and testing. Econometrica, 55,251-276.
Faini, R., Clavijo,
F., & Senhadji-Semlali, A. (1992), The fallacy of composition argument. Is it
relevant for LDCs‟ manufactures exports? European Economic Review, 36,865-82.
Felipe, J., McCombie,
J. S. L. & Naqvi, K. (2009). Is Pakistan‟s growth rate Balance-of-Payments constrained?
Policies and implications for development and growth. Asian Development Economics
Working Paper Series No. 160, May.
Fujita, M., Kuroiwa,
I., & Kumagai, S. (2011). The Economics of East Asian Integration, Cheltenham,
UK: Edward Elgar.
Gregory, A. W.,
& Hansen, B. E. (1996). Residual-based tests for cointegration in models with
regime shifts. Journal of Econometrics, 70,99-126.
Hodrick, R. J.,
& Prescott, E. C. (1997). Postwar U. S. Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation.
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 29,1–16.
Hussain, M. N.
(1999). The Balance of Payment Constraint and Growth Rate Differences among African
and East Asian Economies. African Development Review, 11 (1), 103-137.
IMF (2012). World
Economic Outlook. Washington D. C. : IMF, April.
Mayer, J. (2003).
The fallacy of composition: A review of the literature. UNCTAD Discussion Papers
No. 166, February.
Otero, J., &
Smith, J. (2000). Testing for cointegration: Power versus frequency of observation
– further Monte Carlo results. Economic Letters, 67,5-9.
Sapsford, D.,
& Chen, J. -R. (1998). The Prebisch-Singer Terms of Trade Hypothesis: Some (Very)
New Evidence. In D. Sapsford, & J. -R. Chen (Eds.), Development Economics
and Policy (pp. 229-232). London: Macmillan.
Sepheri, A.,
& Akram-Lodhi, A. H. (2005). Transition, Savings and Growth in Vietnam: A Three-gap
Analysis. Journal of International Development, 17,553-574.
Thirlwall, A.
P. (1979). The Balance of Payments Constraint as an Explanation of International
Growth Rate Differences. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review, 128,45-53.
Thirwall, A.
P. (2002). The Nature of Economic Growth. An Alternative Framework for Understanding
the Performance of Nations. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Thirlwall, A.
P. (2012). Balance of Payments Constrained Growth Models: History and Overview.
In E. Soukiazis, & P. A. Cerqueira (Eds.), Models of Balance of Payments
Constrained Growth: History, Theory and Empirical Evidence (pp. 11-49). Basingstoke:
Palgrave MacMillan, forthcoming.
UNCTAD (2008).
South-South Trade in Asia: The Role of Regional Trade Agreements. New-York
and Geneva: United Nations and JETRO.
World Bank (1993).
The East Asian Miracle. Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank (2008).
Vietnam Development Report 2009: Capital Matters. Hanoi: Vietnam Consultative
Group Meeting, December.
World Bank (2011).
Vietnam Development Report 2012: Market Economy for a Middle income Country.
Hanoi: Vietnam Consultative Group Meeting, December.
APPENDIX A. COUNTRIES
Group A (Developing
Asia, DA): Bangladesh, Bhutan, Cambodia, China, India, Indonesia, Lao PDR, Malaysia,
Mongolia, Nepal, Pakistan, Philippines, Sri Lanka, Thailand.
Group B (Rest Of Asia,
ROA): Australia, Brunei, French Polynesia, Hong-Kong, Japan, Macao, New Caledonia,
New Zealand, North. Mariana Islands, Singapore, South Korea.
Group C (EU15): Austria,
Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg,
Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, United Kingdom.
Group D: USA
Group E: Rest of the
World (ROW)
APPENDIX B. DATA SOURCES AND DEFINITIONS
The bilateral
trade flows of Vietnam to and from each partner region were reconstructed using
the COMTRADE database. The sample runs from 1985 through 2010. Missing data in the
bilateral trade series were reconstructed as follows: If either of the two flows
is missing, we use its “mirror”. If instead
they are both reported but with different values, the bilateral series are reconstructed
as a weighted average of the import and the export ones (where imports receive a
2/3 weight). The data on the bilateral trade relations between Vietnam and the ROW
are missing from the beginning of the sample through 1997. The two series were reconstructed
taking for each the difference between the total flow, extracted from the World
Development Indicators (WDI) Database, and the sum of the other bilateral flows.
Then we calculated the ROW flows by subtracting from the total the other four bilateral
trade series.
Since the COMTRADE
series are in USD at current prices, in order to get their real counterparts, the
import series Mj were deflated using country j aggregate export deflator
(evaluated as the ratio of nominal to real exports in USD), while the export series
Xj were deflated using Vietnam export deflator (evaluated accordingly). Vietnam
export deflator was missing from 1985 to 1988.
The missing data were retropolated using the GDP deflator growth rate. The data
on nominal and real aggregate exports and GDP come from the 2012 edition of the
WDI database. All real variables are measured in USD at 2000 prices.
Relative prices
were constructed as the ratio of domestic prices (measured by Vietnam export deflator)
To foreign prices (measured by partner j GDP deflator). The estimation was
also performed using a “terms of trade”
variable constructed as the ratio of Vietnam export deflator to the partner export
deflator (i. E. To Vietnam import deflator). The empirical results (available upon
request) Did not compare favourably with the one presented in the paper.
APPENDIX C. UNIT ROOT TESTS
As well known,
the results of unit root tests are strongly dependent on the correct specification
of the deterministic component (drift and trend) Of the underlying Data Generating
Process (DGP). Misspecification of the deterministic component may entail a loss
of power (see Campbell & Perron, 1991). In order to cope with this issue, we
adopted the testing strategy proposed by Elder and Kennedy (2001). In short, this
strategy uses the a priori information, provided by the pattern of the time
series, in order to rule out those alternative hypotheses that are inconsistent
with the observed behavior of the data. This allows the researcher to decide on
both the correct specification of the deterministic component and
the presence of a unit root using a single test, thus reducing the multiple hypotheses
testing issues presented by other testing strategies (such as the one proposed by
Dolado, Jenkinson, & Sosvilla-Rivero, 1990).
First, the plot
of the series is inspected, in order to verify whether it exhibits a trending behavior.
If the series is trending, we perform an F test for the null hypothesis H0:
=1, =0 in the model:
yt = + t + yt-1 + t
This F
statistic has a non-standard distribution under the null and is compared with the
critical values of the 3 statistic provided by Dickey and Fuller (1979). Failure
to reject the null implies that the series is I (1) With drift, while rejection
implies that it is I (0) Around a deterministic trend (i. E. <1, 0).
The other possible alternatives are ruled out, being inconsistent with the observed
data behavior (see Elder & Kennedy, 2001).
If instead the
series does not display a regular trending behavior, we test the null hypothesis
H0: =1, =0 in the model:
yt = + yt-1 + t
In this case
the F statistics follows the 1 distribution by Dickey and Fuller (1979).
Failure to reject implies that the series is I (1) Without drift, while rejection
implies that the series was generated by an I (0) Process with unconditional
mean different from zero. In both cases, lags of the differenced dependent variable
were added to the equation in order to whiten its residuals. The lag length was
determined by reduction, starting from a maximum order of lags equal to 2, which
was deemed appropriate considering the sample length and the fact that we are using
annual data.
The results of
the tests are summarized in Table A1, while the Figures from A1 to A4 illustrate
the time series pattern of the data. Starting from the latter, all the variables,
except relative prices, display a clear trending behavior, that could be compatible
with either a I (1) With drift process, or with a I (0) Process with
deterministic trend. The relative price series, instead, display a pronounced reversal
occurring at the beginning of the 1990s, which is incompatible with the presence
of a deterministic trend. The results show that in all cases we were unable to reject
the unit root null. Table A1 - Unit root tests
For trending series we applied the 3 test and for non-trending series the
1 test by Dickey and Fuller (1981). The 5% critical values are 7.24 and 5.18 respectively.
The unit root null is never rejected by the data.
Figure A1 - Real
GDP, logarithmic scale (Vietnam is plotted against the right-hand scale)
Figure A2 - Real
exports, logarithmic scale
Figure A3 - Real
imports, logarithmic scale
Figure A4 - Real
exchange rates, logarithmic scale
FIGURES
Sources: Trade
balance, UN COMTRADE and General Statistics Office of Vietnam (GSO); Current account
balance, IMF World Economic Outlook.
Figure 1 – Vietnam‟s external balance
Source: World
Bank World Development Indicators
Figure 2 – Vietnam‟s export and GDP deflators
Export market
shares
Import market
shares
Figure 3 – Export and import market shares (respectively
in volume and in value)
Figure 4 – The
HP series of BoP equilibrium and actual growth rates
TABLES
Table 1 – Bilateral
imports equations, Engle and Granger estimation
The t-statistics
are reported in italic under the coefficient estimates. DW is the statistic of the
Durbin-Watson test, CRADF is the cointegrating residual augmented Dickey-Fuller
test. An asterisk indicates rejection at the 10% level.
j0 is
the intercept, j0 the shift in the intercept, i, j the relative
prices elasticity, i, j the income elasticity. The t-statistics are
reported in italic under the coefficient estimates. DW is the statistic of the Durbin-Watson
test, ADF* Is the statistic of the Gregory and Hansen test for the null of non cointegration.
One (two, three) Asterisk indicates a 10% (5%, 1%) Significant statistic.
Table 3 – Bilateral
exports equations, Engle and Granger estimation
The t-statistics
are reported in italic under the coefficient estimates. DW is the statistic of the
Durbin-Watson test, CRADF is the cointegrating residual augmented Dickey-Fuller
test. An asterisk indicates rejection at the 10% level.
j0 is
the intercept, j0 the shift in the intercept, j, i, the relative
prices elasticity, j, i, the income elasticity. The t-statistics
are reported in italic under the coefficient estimates. DW is the statistic of the
Durbin-Watson test, ADF* Is the statistic of the Gregory and Hansen test
for the null of non cointegration against the alternative of a level shift. One
(two, three) Asterisk indicates a 10% (5%, 1%) Significant statistic.
Table 5 – A summary
of the estimated elasticities
Table 6 – Comparison
between the BoP equilibrium and the actual growth rates
Table 7 – Some projections on Vietnam‟s economic growth (2011-2017)
Không có nhận xét nào:
Đăng nhận xét