Assessing the Cost of Protection in Vietnam After Becoming WTO’s Member
Nguyen Anh Thu
1.Introduction
Since the economic reform in 1986, Vietnam has experienced extremely quick integration into the world market.
Trade volume has increased sharply and the composition of Vietnam’s trading partners has broadened.
Trade turnover in 1990 was roughly 6.2 billion USD, however, in 2005 it reached 69.2 billion USD and that of 2008 has been 143.4 billion USD.
The growth of Vietnam’s trading rate in 2000─2005 period is 18.4%, which is 2.6 times the growth rate of Vietnam’s GDP. At the same time, the number of trading
partners has increased,
of which Asian countries constitute the most important
trading partners of Vietnam,
accounting for more than 50% of Vietnam’s trade.
Vietnam has
become WTO
member in
2006, which is one
big step
of its
integration into
the world market. Becoming WTO’s member means that Vietnam has to fulfill its obligations regarding reducing tariffs, opening markets for foreign
products but at the same time it can have more access
to foreign markets.
Although the objective of WTO is freer trade all over the world, its negotiations of the Doha Round have been halted for a long time (Jones,
2009). Almost all countries in the world including Vietnam still maintain many restrictions on the movements
of goods across borders. As widely accepted in economics, this will reduce surplus or gains from trade of all countries engaged. Restrictions of Vietnam on imports and restrictions of other countries on Vietnam’s export will reduce the consumers’ choices and will divert resources from industries where there are comparative advantages.
This paper’s objective is to estimate
the welfare cost of protection in Vietnam before and after it became WTO member.
Although the welfare cost of protection is confirmed in economics theory, the structure of protection in Vietnam is vivid (Prema-chandra Athukorala, 2006), quantitative analyses on Vietnam’s welfare cost of protection are still limited.
This paper applies
gravity model to Vietnam’s trade data to evaluate
trade potential and welfare cost of protection in Vietnam. It will then use the result of the regression to further estimate
the effect of protection on the volume of Vietnam’s trade and to obtain rough estimates of the resulting
welfare effects before and after Vietnam became WTO member.
2.Methodology and data
1.Model identification
Gravity model was first applied to international trade by Tinbergen (1962) And Pöynöhen (1963). The basic and simplest
form of gravity model for international trade posits that the volume of trade between two trading partners
is an increasing function
of their national income, and a decreasing function of the distance between them.
Gravity model was widely used in trade because most of its regressions fit data remarkably
well (Anderson and Wincoop, 2003). However,
The model was criticized
for lacking a theoretical basis. Works by Anderson
(1979), Helpman and Krugman (1985) And Bergstrand (1985) Showed that gravity equations
could be derived from trade models with product differentiation and increasing returns to scale. Deardorff (1998) Contributed to gravity model theoretical basis by showing that the gravity equation
is consistent with several variants
of the Ricardian and Heckscher-Ohlin models.
Gravity model is applied to answer many questions
related to trade. Among them, a number of gravity analyses
deal with various trade policy issues, such as the effects of national borders, the merits of proposed regional trade arrangements and the effects
of protection and openness (Anderson
et al., 2001 and Arvind Panagariya, 2002). Wall (1999) Applied gravity model to US trade data to estimate the effects of protection on the volume of US trade and roughly estimate the resulting
welfare effects. Although the theoretical calculations of the cost of trade protection are well established, the empirical estimates
of the costs are still very small due to the lack of estimation method and data. Wall (1999)
Has provided a new method of estimating the costs of protection by applying gravity
model, which requires less information than previous methods but still has the advantages of general equilibrium approach.
The estimations of Wall (1999) Are much higher than in previous
studies such as Baldwin
(1984), Feenstra (1992), Hufbauer
and Karen (1994), who found that cost of protection of the U. S. Was
only 0.38 to 0.73% of the U. S. GDP.
The reason for this low estimation is the use of partial equilibrium method. Wall
(1999) Had used the gravity model to have general equilibrium approach.
In this paper, the model of Wall (1999) Is
applied to trade data of Vietnam with its main trading
partners for the period 2004─2008 in order
to estimate the welfare cost of trade protection in Vietnam. The regression equation will take the form:
LnTijt = a
+ þ1Ln[Yit ]+ þ2 Ln J(Y/ P) ] + þ3 LnYjt + þ4 Ln J(Y/ P) ]
[ it ] [
jt ]
þ5 Dij + þ6 ASEANij +þ7 SCij + þ8 Indexjt + þ9WTOt
Indexjt + sijt ⑴
Where Tijt is the export or import of Vietnam
to a partner country in the year t. Yit is the GDP of exporting country, (Y/P) It is the GDP per capita for the exporting country. J stands for importing country. D is the distance between the capital of Vietnam─Hanoi─and the capital city of the partner country. Index is the trade policy index for the
Importing country,
and ɛ is an error term. To address characteristics of Vietnam’s trade
patterns, three dummy variables
Were added: Traditional trade partner variable─SC (Socialist country), ASEAN trade network variable─ASEAN, and Vietnam’s WTO membership variable─WTO. In order to capture the relation
between trade index and the WTO membership, the model
introduces the interaction term between trade index variable
and WTO membership dummy.
2.Data
The data set is Vietnam’s merchandise imports and exports to and from 84 countries for the period 2004─2008. The data are obtained from UNCOMTRADE statistics. Table 1 shows 10 biggest
trading partners of Vietnam and their bilateral trade with Vietnam in 2008.
National income data─GDP and per capita GDP are taken from the IMF statistics. All the trade data and GDP are
Converted into US dollars. The distance variable is the great-circle distance between Hanoi and capital city of
the trading partner.
In order to quantify
the level of freedom, the paper use trade policy index that is part of the Index of Economic Freedom published by the Heritage Foundation.
The indices are calculated based on two inputs:
The trade weighted average of tariffs
and the non-tariff barriers
(NTBs). NTBs include: Quantity restrictions, price restrictions, regulatory restrictions, investment restrictions, customs restrictions and the government direct interventions. The level of trade
Table 1 Top 10 Trading
Partners of Vietnam (2008)
(In thousand US dollars)
|
Country
|
Trade turnover
|
export
|
import
|
1
|
China
|
20,823,661
|
4850109
|
15973552
|
2
|
USA
|
14,554,848
|
11902833
|
2652014
|
3
|
Japan
|
16,708,057
|
8467749
|
8240307
|
4
|
Singapore
|
12,091,799
|
2713824
|
9377975
|
5
|
Korea
|
9,048,705
|
1793525
|
7255179
|
6
|
Thailand
|
6,194,167
|
1288546
|
4905620
|
7
|
Australia
|
5,709,476
|
4351579
|
1357897
|
8
|
Malaysia
|
4,626,454
|
2030402
|
2596052
|
9
|
Germany
|
3,553,332
|
2073423
|
1479908
|
10
|
Hong Kong
|
3,510,506
|
877189
|
2633317
|
Source: UNCOMTRADE statistics
Table
2 Top 10 Countries in Trade Policy Index (2008)
|
Country
|
Trade policy index
|
1
|
Hong Kong
|
95
|
2
|
Singapore
|
90
|
3
|
Switzerland
|
87.2
|
4
|
Canada
|
87
|
5
|
USA
|
86.8
|
6
|
Turkey
|
86.8
|
7
|
Israel
|
86.6
|
8
|
Kazakhstan
|
86.2
|
9
|
Norway
|
86.2
|
10
|
Germany
|
86
|
Source:
Index of Economic Freedom 2008─The Heritage
Foundation
Freedom (or protection) Of a country is judged on a scale 0 to 100, where 100 is the ideal free of trade.
Table 2 reported 10 countries having
highest trade policy
indices in 2008.
According to this scale, Vietnam’s score is 54.8 in 2004 and 62.8 in 2008, which is relatively low and means quite
High level of protection. In 2005, Vietnam weighted average
tariff rate was 13.6% and that of 2008 is 10.7%. Although the Government has made progress in liberalizing trade volume, NTBs still account for 10% point deduction in Vietnam’ s free trade score.
As listed by Heritage Foundation, those NTBs are import bans and restrictions, service market access barriers, import licensing requirements,
nontransparent regulations, state trade
in some commodities, weak enforcement of intellectual property
rights, corruption and customs inconsistency.
Table
3 Regressions
Results for Gravity Model of Vietnamʼs
Trade in
2004‒2008
Dependent
Variable: Log of bilateral exports
Coefficient
|
Std. Error
|
t-Statistic
|
Prob.
|
|
Constant
|
12.22
|
1.29
|
9.50
|
0.00
|
Origin GDP (log)
|
0.93
|
0.06
|
15.91
|
0.00
|
Origin GDP per capita (log)
|
-0.10
|
0.06
|
-1.67
|
0.10
|
Destination GDP (log)
|
0.60
|
0.06
|
10.16
|
0.00
|
Destination GDP per capita (log)
|
0.04
|
0.09
|
0.50
|
0.62
|
Distance
(log)
|
-0.99
|
0.13
|
-7.70
|
0.00
|
ASEAN
|
0.80
|
0.34
|
2.33
|
0.02
|
Socialist
|
-0.16
|
0.17
|
-0.91
|
0.36
|
Trade policy index
|
0.02
|
0.01
|
1.89
|
0.06
|
WTO* Index
|
0.00
|
0.00
|
0.99
|
0.32
|
R-squared 0.65
|
||||
Observations 840
|
3.Empirical results
Two least squared
regressions of the gravity models were performed. The first, as described
in ⑴, is under the restriction that the trading-pair intercepts are all equal, and the second, as in ⑵, relaxed this restriction by including
fixed effects to control
for unobservable pair-specific effects.
However, the fixed effects
were found insignificant.
LnTijt = a
+ þ1Ln[Yit ]+ þ2 Ln J(Y/ P) ] + þ3 LnYjt + þ4 Ln J(Y/ P) ]
[ it ] [
jt ]
þ5 Indexjt +þ6WTOt * Indexjt + sijt ⑵
Although the
restriction equation (1) Assumed that trading-pair intercepts are all
equal, it
has included many explanatory variables which might capture
specific effects
of the trading pairs.
The results of this regression are reported in Table 3. Most of the explanatory variables
are found to be significant. The coefficients of GDP have positive sign and has the value of 0.93 for exporting countries
and 0.60 for importing country,
which indicate that Vietnam trades more with the countries of bigger economic
size. This result is consistent with the basic hypothesis of the gravity
model.
In contrast, the estimation shows that
the per
capita GDP
variables are
not significant factors in
explaining Vietnam’s trade volumes. This implies that trade volumes
of Vietnam much depend on the size of
the partner economy
rather than on the per capita income.
The empirical result is different from that of Frankel (1997), in which a predicted
1% increase in per capita
GDP leads to about 0.1% increase in bilateral trade volume.
The distance variable is
statistically significant with expected negative coefficient, meaning that geographical distance is an important factor in reducing
Vietnam’s trade volume.
ASEAN variable is highly significant with the expected
coefficient of 0.80. This
implies the increase
of 0.8% in trade volume of Vietnam with the partner country if the partner is an ASEAN member. High trade flows due to lower tariff and other trade facilitating commitments of ASEAN Free
Trade Area (AFTA), which aims at 0─5% tariffs for all goods
traded among ASEAN member countries. In contrast, the Socialist
variable’s coefficient has negative
sign and is
Table
4 Effects of Protection on Vietnamʼs
Imports and Exports (2004)
|
Actual Vietnam’s trade (thousands US dollars)
|
Effects of protection (thousands US dollars)
|
Effects of protection as percent of
trade
|
Effects of protection as percent of Vietnam’s GDP
|
Vietnam’s Imports
|
||||
From countries in sample
|
28,166,299
|
12,195,468
|
-43.3
|
-30.39
|
From all countries
|
31,968,820
|
13,842,499
|
-43.3
|
|
Vietnam’s Exports
|
||||
To countries in the sample
|
25,225,697
|
12,380,118
|
-49.07
|
-28.53
|
To all countries
|
26,485,035
|
12,996,207
|
-49.07
|
Table 5
Effects of Protection on Vietnamʼs Imports and Exports
(2008)
|
Actual Vietnam’s trade (thousands US dollars)
|
Effects of protection (thousands US dollars)
|
Effects of protection as percent of
trade
|
Effects of protection as percent of Vietnam’s GDP
|
Vietnam’s Imports
|
||||
From countries in sample
|
71,660,127
|
10,070,641
|
-14.05
|
-12.62
|
From all countries
|
80,713,829
|
11,340,292
|
-14.05
|
|
Vietnam’s Exports
|
||||
To countries in the sample
|
60,146,137
|
17,172,225
|
-28.55
|
-19.92
|
To all countries
|
62,685,129
|
17,896,604
|
-28.55
|
Insignificant, which means that Vietnam’s trade pattern
does not depend on the former partners.
Coefficient on trade policy index is positive and significant at 10% level, showing that Vietnam will trade more with countries
of lower protection
or higher level of trade freedom.
The interaction term between trade policy index and
WTO membership dummy is found insignificant in this regression. This can be explained
by the fact that Vietnam became WTO member in 2007, however, some of its commitments have been performed
before 2007, and many of them will be fulfilled
in the following years. Therefore, it requires longer time for this variable
to show its significant effect on Vietnam’s trade.
4.Welfare cost of protection
To calculate the total effects
of Vietnam’s protection on Vietnam’s import
and protection of other countries
on Vietnam’s export, the regression results are applied to the data of 2004 and 2008. Firstly, the paper calculated the volume of goods that Vietnam would have imported
from the countries
in the sample if Vietnam has no protection, i. E.
The trade policy index equal to 100.
Secondly, it then calculated
the volume of goods that Vietnam would have exported to other countries
in the sample if those countries have no protection. Finally, assuming that the effect of protection as percentage of trade is the same for the countries within and outside the sample, we will have the overall effect of protection on Vietnam’s trade with all the countries in the world. The results of these calculations are shown in Table 4 and Table 5.
Table 4 obviously
shows that, in 2004, Vietnam imported
more than 31.9 billion U. S. Dollar of goods from other countries, but would have imported
13.8 billion more if Vietnam had the
policy of free trade. This means that protection has reduced the imports of Vietnam
by 49.07%. Given the fact that Vietnam’s GDP is quite small
and trade contributes greatly to GDP, this number amounts for about 30.39% of Vietnam GDP. By the empirical study of Wall (1999) For the year 1996,
protection has caused
to the U. S. 15.4% reduction in import, which
is about 1.66%
of U. S. GDP.
For the export side, Vietnam exported more than 26.4 billion U. S. Dollar of goods to other countries
in 2004, but would have exported 12.9
billions more if other countries had free
trade. Protection decreased the amount of Vietnam’ s export by 47.07%, which
was 28.53% of Vietnam’s GDP. For the U. S. In 1996,
Wall (1999) Estimated the reduction of 26.2% of export, which equals to 1.94% of GDP.
The results of 2008 have proved that the implementation of Vietnam’s commitments under WTO have significantly reduced the relative welfare
cost of protection of Vietnam (Table 5). Specifically, the cost of protection for imported products in 2008 accounted for only 14.05% of trade, compared to 43.3% in 2004. Moreover, protection of other countries’ to Vietnam has reduced export of Vietnam by 28.55%, which is much lower than that of 2004.
This fact clearly shows the benefits of joining WTO to Vietnam,
although the fulfillment of Vietnam’s commitments under WTO is still limited
(Roland-Holst, 2002 and Thanh, 2005).
5.Conclusion
By using Vietnam’s bilateral trade data with 84 countries
for the period 2004─2008 to estimate gravity
model, this paper has found main influential
factors on Vietnam’s trade, which are GDP, distance,
ASEAN membership and trade policy index. These estimations follow closely the basic hypothesis of gravity model.
By using the results of the regressions to data of 2004 and 2008, the paper roughly estimates the welfare cost of protection of Vietnam’s before and after Vietnam became WTO member. Obviously, the relative welfare cost of protection has decreased along with the fulfillment of Vietnam commitments under WTO.
These results suggest the widely accepted
and supported idea by economists: Countries will gain from free trade. ASEAN Free Trade Area
(AFTA) Is also a good evidence for the advantage
of free trade. That is, its membership has increased Vietnam’s trade volume
with member countries
by about 0.8%. By
becoming WTO member in 2007, Vietnam is on the way to reduce its tariffs and eliminate NTBs, with the hope to obtain
more gains from trade.
References
Anderson, J.
E. (1979), “A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity
Equation”, American
Economic Review, Vol. 69, pp.
106─116. Anderson J. E. And Wincoop E. V. (2003), “Gravity
with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle”, American Economic
Review,
Vol. 93, pp. 170─192.
Anderson K., Francois
J., Hertel T., Hoekman
B. And Martin W. (2001), “The Cost of Rich (and Poor)
Country Protection to Developing Countries”, Journal of African Economy, Vol. 10, Issue 3, pp.
227─257.
Arvind Panagariya (2002), “Cost of
Protection: Where Do We Stand?”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 92, Issue 2, pp. 175─ 179.
Baldwin, R. E. (1984), “Trade Policies in Developed Countries,” Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 1, Ronald W. Jones and Peter B. Kenen, eds., North-Holland, pp. 571─619.
Bergstrand, J. H. (1985), “The Gravity Equation in International Trade: Some Microeconomic
Foundations and Empirical Evidence”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 67, pp.
474─481.
Deardorff, V. A. (1998), “Determinants
of Bilateral Trade: Does Gravity Work in a Neoclassical World?”, The Regionalization of the World Economy, Jeffrey A. Frankel, ed., University of Chicago Press, pp.
7─28.
Feenstra R.
C. (1992), “How Costly is
Protectionism?”, Journal
of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 6, pp.
159─178. Frankel, J., (1997), “Regional Trading Blocks”, Institute for International Economics, Washington,
DC.
Helpman E., Krugman
P. (1985), “Market
Structure and Foreign Trade: Increasing Returns, Imperfect Competition, and the
International Economy”, The Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Hufbauer G. C. And
Karen A. E. (1994), “Measuring the Costs of
Protection in the United States”, Institute for International Economics.
Jones K. (2009), The Doha Blues: Institutional Crisis and Reform in the WTO, Oxford University Press,
Inc.
Prema-chandra Athukorala (2006), “Trade Policy Reforms and the
Structure of Protection in Vietnam”, The World Economy, Vol.
29, Issue 2, pp. 161─187.
Pöyhönen P. (1963), “A
Tentative Model for the Volume of Trade between countries”, Weltwirtschaftliches Archive, Vol. 90, pp.
93─100.
Roland-Holst, D., Tarp, F., An, D. V., Thanh,
V. T., Huong, P. L.
And Minh, D. H. (2002), Vietnam’s Accession to the World Trade Organization: Economic Projections to 2020, CIEM/NIAS Discussion Paper
DP0204.
Thanh, V. T. (2005) Vietnam’s Trade Liberalization and International Economic Integration: Evolution, Problems and Challenges,
ASEAN Economic Bulletin, Vol. 22, Issue 1, pp. 75─91.
Tinbergen J. (1962), “Shaping the World
Economy─Suggestions for an International Economic Policy”, The Twenty Century Fund.
Wall J. H. (1999), “Using the Gravity Model to
Estimate the Costs of Protection”, January/February Review of Federal Bank of Saint Louis, pp. 33─40.
IMF data and
statistics: Http: // imf. Org/external/ns/cs. Aspx? Id=28
Index of Economic Freedom
2008─The Heritage Foundation: Http: // heritage. Org/Index/Ranking. Aspx
UNCOMTRADE statistics:
Comtrade. Un. Org/db/default.
Aspx
[グェン アン トウ ベトナム国家大学講師,横浜国立大学大学院国際社会科学研究科博士課程修了]
====================
>> More document reseach in Science
==================
Không có nhận xét nào:
Đăng nhận xét